Explaining the Cross Section of Commodity Returns
What’s the most useful way to look at commodity prices?
Some say it’s best to consider the storage and convenience yield — the benefit of holding the asset itself, rather than the contract or derivative. That inkling, and the hedging motives of producers, consumers and speculators has sparked various theories about the behavior of commodity futures prices and has spearheaded efforts to understand the economic drivers of commodity risk premia.
Still, questions remained unanswered: Which asset pricing models are capable of reconciling the cross-sectional properties of commodity futures returns, at both the portfolio and individual commodity levels? What is a possible explanation for the positive average returns of the commodity carry and momentum factors? How are the commodity pricing factors related to innovations in economic variables? How should one interpret the behavior of the commodity factors over the different stages of the business cycle?
In new research, a team from the University of Maryland’s Robert H. Smith School of Business sought to answer those questions.
The research was authored by Gurdip Bakshi, the Smith School Dean’s Professor of Finance; Xiaohui Gao Bakshi, visiting professor of finance at the Smith School, and Alberto Rossi, assistant professor of finance at the Smith School.
The researchers examined commodity futures returns over a 42-year period, beginning in 1970. They studied baseline portfolios, managed portfolios and individual commodities, and found that a three-factor model — driven by an average factor, a carry factor, and a momentum factor — outperformed the nested one- and two-factor counterparts in capturing the cross-section of commodity returns. And they drafted an analysis, centering on an economic explanation of the commodity factors.
The carry strategy, they found, performs poorly when global stock volatility increases, and innovations in global equity volatility can price portfolios sorted on carry. “The economic intuition is that investors dislike these adverse changes in the investment opportunity set and require positive average returns to carry as compensation,” the researchers say.
But they had a harder time explaining commodity momentum, because no traditional macroeconomic variable appeared to satisfactorily explain the returns on such strategy. The researchers did find, however, that the momentum strategy performed well when aggregate speculative activity increases, and innovations in aggregate speculative activity can price portfolios sorted on momentum.
Because commodity speculators are known to follow momentum strategies, the researchers viewed the finding as evidence that whenever more agents in the market behave as momentum traders, momentum strategies self-perpetuate. Commodities whose prices have been increasing continue to increase in price, while the commodities whose prices have been decreasing continue to decrease in price.
Among their other findings, the researchers found three “worth emphasizing.”
- First, innovations in global equity volatility cannot price momentum portfolios, and innovations in speculative activity cannot price carry portfolios.
- Second, the authors’ measure of speculative activity is specific to commodity markets and is unrelated to many proxies that capture the availability of arbitrage capital and liquidity constructed from the equity and bond markets.
- And third, neither carry nor momentum portfolios can be priced by innovations in many other economic variables.
Read more: Understanding the Sources of Risk Underlying the Cross-Section of Commodity Returns is featured in Management Science.
Media Contact
Greg Muraski
Media Relations Manager
301-405-5283
301-892-0973 Mobile
gmuraski@umd.edu
Get Smith Brain Trust Delivered To Your Inbox Every Week
Business moves fast in the 21st century. Stay one step ahead with bite-sized business insights from the Smith School's world-class faculty.